Douglass C. North passed away on Nov. 23, 2015, at the age of 95. A recipient of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics, he was one of the most cited and influential scholars of his generation—not just in economics, but also in law, political science, history, and development. Though he started as a conscientious objector and even a Marxist before World War 2, North's views constantly evolved and in the end, he did more than anyone to restore to the study of economics the importance of good institutions as the basis for the success of modern market capitalism.
Today, the idea that good formal and informal institutions (laws, norms, and their enforcement characteristics)—the rules of the game as he called them—are a crucial determinant of economic success or failure is almost a trite truism accepted by academics, NGOs, and most governments from Mumbai to Moscow, and from Berkeley to Beijing. So it is difficult to recall a time half a century ago, when most leading economists and bureaucrats could say or suggest that all that mattered for development were new technologies, capital transfer, and good Keynesian management of employment and aggregate demand. Leading surveys of growth in the 1950s were written as if the only differences between the economies of the United States, France, Sweden, and the Soviet Union were due to unemployment, technology transfer, capital accumulation, and demand management.
North changed that by arguing even as far back as the Industrial Revolution, it made no sense to focus on technological change without considering the role of property rights, reliable systems of law and order, and reasonably liberal economic policy. Though North was a big promoter of the use of economics and statistics in history, he was a critic of the narrow way in which neoclassical economics was used and the tendency—still current in the profession—to let the latest techniques determine which problems were important or acceptable for publication.
But North was remarkable in the extent to which he welcomed criticism of his work and relished a good intellectual fight, without bearing a grudge or feeling any animosity. He told me with pleasure that until just before he received the Nobel, none of his books received positive reviews.
As a young Ph.D. student at Northwestern, I struggled to get a word in edgewise when North came up from St. Louis to give a talk, as all the senior faculty were hell-bent on knocking down North's latest ideas. But he came up to me afterwards to ask for my comments and then directed me to write him a detailed letter with all my criticisms of his work. A few weeks later, I was offered an interview by Washington University in St. Louis. I eventually joined Doug as a colleague and I remained at WUSTL working alongside him for 22 years.
There, he was not only a terrific friend, mentor, and colleague, but a driving force behind St. Louis becoming a center of the New Institutional Economics for two decades, from 1983 to the early 2000s. He was so generous with his time and support with students and friends that the laws of physics must have bent around him. It can be said of few men like North, that he was a great scholar but an even greater human being. Many will mourn his passing.
Comments