In Capital in the Twenty-First Century, the French economist Thomas Piketty claims to have uncovered "the central contradiction of capitalism." When a major scholar like Piketty-a man who has contributed real value to empirical economics-makes such a bold claim, it deserves to be taken seriously.
So what is this flaw at the heart of the economic machine, a flaw somehow overlooked by economists for centuries? That sometimes the interest rate (which Piketty correctly uses as a stand-in for the total average return on different types of capital, including profits, interest, and capital gains) is greater than the overall economic growth rate. Piketty sums this concept up with the simple equation: r > g. If r > g for decades, he argues, capital's advantage contains the seeds of deep social conflict.
If the wealth of capitalists grows at the interest rate, and if that wealth grows faster than the overall economy, capitalists will take over more and more of the economy until something genuinely awful happens, goes the idea. Piketty is vague about what this awfulness might consist of, but the memory of the last century brings to mind quite a few unpleasant scenarios in which average citizens get mad at elites: anything from banking overregulation to a full-blown Marxist revolution, with dozens of possibilities in between. In the meantime, ultra-wealthy economic elites can buy massive political influence, prodding the government to favor well-connected insiders and thus slow down the economy.
As a matter of politics rather than economics, there's little to disagree with Piketty's prophecy. If-a big if-there's a central contradiction in capitalism that makes capitalists get richer at a faster rate than the overall economy, then the miracle of compound interest promises endless opportunities for conflict between those with compounding wealth and those with slow-growing wages.
So is this central contradiction a thing? Barely. Even capitalists consume, and they can consume quite a lot. The typical person might not be able to imagine what it's like to be worth a billion dollars and have about $40 million a year in interest and dividend income as spending money, but among private jets, new cars, the latest medical treatments, and gifts for rich friends, a billionaire can spend that much just trying to keep up with his neighbors. Saving is mostly just delayed consumption, as generations of economists have taught, and the only way for capital to grow exactly at the interest rate is for nobody to consume it. Every bit of consumption pushes down the growth rate of capital.
The entrepreneur who earns a few billion from innovation might be frugal enough to pass on a massively compounded pile of capital. But descendants have a funny way of frittering away fortunes or at least dividing it into tiny slices, causing the long-run trend of this pile of billionaire capital to grow at about the same rate as the overall economy.
Since capital helps the average worker do her job, we should hope that the world's billionaires will be frugal rather than reckless, lending their stockpile to fund innovation the world over. But we are unlikely to be so lucky. Billionaire wealth can turn into multimillionaire wealth with just a few ill-judged marriages.
There's an extra reason to think that capital isn't going to permanently grow at a faster rate than the overall economy: Piketty says it won't. While r > g suggests total capital is growing faster than total wages forever, Piketty occasionally reminds his readers that "divergence is not perpetual" and that his conclusions are "less apocalyptic" than "Marx's principle of infinite accumulation." The author places great weight on the mainstream economic idea that the natural long-term tendency of market economies is for capital and the economy to both grow at about the same rate. That "twin growth rate" might be high if population and technology are advancing quickly, or it might be low if both are in the doldrums, but there's no inherent tendency for capital to outpace the economy forever, even if Piketty's "central contradiction" of high interest rates holds.
The reason is simple. If the first capital investment (think of a machine) is more productive than the second-i.e., if there are diminishing returns for buying new machines, and if the things wear out and fall apart at a fairly predictable rate (a depreciation rate, in accounting-speak)-then in the very long run, the real barrier to faster capital growth is the ability to replace the worn-out machines.
We see this whenever the capital stock grows at high rates for decades, as in post-war Europe or post-Mao China: These economies eventually end up devoting enormous resources just to replacing and repairing the ever-growing pile of decaying buildings, rusting factories, and broken vehicles. The Keynesian economist Robert Solow made the point clear to generations of economists. As long as the law of diminishing returns is true for machines and equipment, he showed, a major barrier to riches is the growing pile of worn-out capital, which gets harder to replace as it expands. And if your economy's ability to replace machines only grows as fast as the rest of the economy, then the economy's growth rate eventually pins down the growth rate of the capital stock.
Beyond this story of engineering is another fact of economic life: the entrepreneur's endless quest for cheaper, better alternatives. High interest rates mean high borrowing costs, so business owners will always be looking for alternatives to capital investments, such as hiring more workers. This quest for substitutes tends to shrink the business world's demand for capital. Together, the growing replacement costs and the quest for cheaper alternatives make it hard to imagine capital continuing to grow as far as the eye can see.
While Piketty's contradiction is less an iron law and more a chalkboard speculation, there's still plenty of room for class warfare in our future. One way to assess whether capitalists are going to exercise unprecedented influence in this struggle is to measure their share of the economy right now, compared to historical levels.
Here, Piketty's arduous research pays off. For the two countries for which he has data going back more than a century, Britain and France, the answer is clear: Capitalists are claiming a substantially smaller share of the economic pie today than they did in the mid-19th century. Back then capital income was a bit more than 40 percent of total national income. Now it's a bit under 30 percent. So if capitalists-savers, landowners, entrepreneurs, and all the rest-are going to become a bigger deal in the future, they've got a long way to go before they're even back at 19th-century levels.
In real life, the categories of "capitalist" and "wage-earner" overlap, as everyone with an IRA or a 401(k) intuits. But Piketty performs a service in demonstrating just how concentrated the ownership of capital is among a smallish group of savers. Housing is a big exception in the United States and a few other countries, and Piketty does a more than adequate job showing readers that many people in rich countries really do have substantial savings in one form or another. For instance, he notes that in European countries there is a "middle class of wealth"-those between the 50th and 90th wealth percentiles-who are worth an average 175,000 euros per adult.
But the concentration at the top is real. Even more important, it's perceived as real by progressive elites and by many voters. A case in point: Piketty refers to the wealth of the European middle classes as merely "a few crumbs."
That brings us to questions of politics and culture. For the next decade or two, inequality will probably continue to increase in rich countries. Even if capital inequality turns out to be less of a central contradiction and more of a bloggable curiosum, rising inequality in wages and salaries is certainly real. In his recent book Average Is Over, my colleague Tyler Cowen argues that we'll see ever more technology-driven wage inequality. While Piketty thinks that changing social norms are at least as important as technology, the source of the inequality may not matter much for politicians, voters, and commentators.
Market-oriented economies that learn to live with inequality will reap rewards: More domestic capital for workers to use on the job, more foreign capital flowing into countries perceived as safe investments, and political/cultural systems that can devote time to topics other than the accursed 1 percent. Market-oriented economies that instead follow Piketty's preferred path-heavily taxing capital, preferably through international consortia so that the taxes are harder to evade-will end up with less domestic and foreign capital, fewer lenders willing to fund new housing projects, fewer new office buildings, and cultural systems focused on who has more and who has less.
Higher taxes on capital deter long-run investment and long-run planning. Reasonable savers care about after-tax returns on their savings, which explains why tax-free municipal bonds are often able to offer lower interest rates than taxable U.S. government bonds. The Boston University economist Christophe Chamley and the Stanford economist Kenneth Judd came up independently with what we might call the Chamley-Judd Redistribution Impossibility Theorem: Any tax on capital is a bad idea in the long run, and the overwhelming effect of a capital tax is to lower wages.
A capital tax is such a bad idea that even if workers and capitalists really were two entirely separate groups of people-if workers could only eat their wages and capitalists just lived off of their interest like a bunch of trust-funders-it would still be impossible to permanently tax capitalists, hand the tax revenues to workers, and make the workers better off.
Why? Because the tax on capital would shrink the supply of machines, which workers use to become more productive and earn more. In the (too) simple world of economic models, the Chamley-Judd result shows that, for instance, a capital tax raising revenue equal to 1 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) would cut wages by more than 1 percent of GDP. It's impossible to "redistribute" income to workers in a way that raises the average worker's total income. What you gain from the government check is more than lost in your weekly paycheck.
Nonetheless, some combination of rising inequality and popular demand for social services for rich countries' aging populations will make the wealthy an ever-easier tax target. Our best hope is cultural change, a move toward calming the country's covetousness. Piketty draws repeatedly on 19th-century novels by Austen and Balzac to illustrate his points, but the poorest 10 percent of people in 19th-century France or England were much poorer than the poorest 10 percent in France or England today. Whatever argument there was in the 19th century for sacrificing long-run economic growth in order to help the poor, that argument is weaker now.
Instead of preaching to reduce inequality as a means to reduce social conflict, we should instead preach to reduce social conflict itself. The best way to defuse the situation is to teach tolerance for inequality. Piketty encourages tolerance for merit-based inequality, for better workers earning more than others, for rewards to frugality, and the like. But we could also use tolerance for luck-based inequality: for the inheritor of a fortune, for the pretty good CEO who gets an eight-figure bonus just because his company's product went viral on Vine. Political battles against inequality produce too many invisible casualties-missing factories, unbuilt apartment complexes-even in the best of cases. And given the intense political world of the aging rich countries, we're unlikely to experience the best-case policy scenarios.
That's why I propose the creation of the 10th Commandment Club. The 10th commandment-"You shall not covet"-has long been a foundation for social peace. The Nobel laureate economist Vernon Smith noted the 10th commandment along with the eighth (you shall not steal) in his Nobel toast, saying that they "provide the property right foundations for markets, and warned that petty distributional jealousy must not be allowed to destroy" those foundations. If academics, pundits, and columnists would avowedly reject covetousness, would openly reject comparisons between the average (extremely fortunate) American and the average billionaire, if they would mock people who claimed that frugal billionaires are a systematic threat to modern life, then soon our time could be spent discussing policy issues that really matter.
People who are genuinely desperate aren't the issue here. The 10th Commandment Club has no qualms with a Jean Valjean stealing bread to feed his family. But the implicit emphasis of Piketty's Capital is comparing the 1 percent (or 0.01 percent) to the typical person living in the G-7, a person who is, on average, more fortunate than most of the world's population and more materially fortunate than almost anyone living in the 19th-century novels that Piketty so loves to discuss. To paraphrase an old P.J. O'Rourke joke, just think about Mr. Darcy's visits to the dentist.
Piketty clearly prefers to talk about the wealth of European and U.S. elites, but he spends a few crucial pages talking about capital accumulation in developing countries. It's here that he notes what may be the most important fact in his book: According to his long-run forecast, "Asian countries should own about half of world capital by the end of the twenty-first century."
The high savings rates in Asia, particularly East Asia, have long puzzled economists. Asian nations with young populations or old, with fast-growing economies or slow, all generally tend to have savings rates as high as or higher than those of comparable economies outside Asia.
If these countries keep on saving at higher-than-average rates, they will create mountains of bountiful capital for decades to come. If capital flows stay free-if money can move to its highest return across the globe, with few tax and regulatory fetters-that means there will be ever more homes and machines available across the world. And a bountiful supply of capital tends to push interest rates in a direction that diminishes whatever is left of Piketty's central contradiction. The "global savings glut" that Ben Bernanke wrote about a decade ago may last quite a while, and that's good for the world's productivity.
Things could change at any time–culture and law are both hard to predict-but traditional economics has a very strong prediction for what happens when some countries are (on average) more patient than others, in a setting where capital can flow freely the world over: In the long run, the patient inherit the earth. As long as nations differ in patience, the patient capitalists start by investing in the less patient countries, and the less patient countries gladly and willingly borrow the cheap cash. The patient countries help increase the capital stock of their less patient neighbors, and-as long as there aren't legal barriers to foreign ownership-in the long run the patient nations end up owning essentially all of the world's capital, while the less patient nations end up sending not only their profits but even most of their mortgaged wages to the patient nations.
One lesson of this story is that it's good to be patient. So let's start training ourselves and our children to delay gratification, to forego that great sound system on the new car, to eat at home a little more often. Another lesson is one that Piketty hits head on: If the world moves toward this outcome, where some rich nations own vast amounts of other rich nations' wealth, we can all expect a political backlash. We could see bans on foreign ownership, discriminatory regulations that end up as de facto bans, confiscation of foreign-owned assets, or something considerably worse.
Hence the need for tolerance. As Piketty reminds us, human beings can be pretty bad at living with economic inequality. But when it comes to capital, simple economic theory is right: the more, the merrier. And if we can reduce covetousness, we can begin to say the reverse: the merrier, the more.
Comments